Who does Senator John McCain (R-Ariz.) think he is fooling?
McCain's
"Climate Stewardship Act" (S. 139), co-sponsored with Senator Joe
Lieberman (D-Conn.), and soon to be voted on in the Senate, started out
as a roadmap back to the Kyoto Protocol, the UN global warming treaty
that President Bush rejected in March 2001. As originally introduced,
McCain's bill would require the United States to reduce emissions of
greenhouse gases, chiefly carbon dioxide (CO2) from fossil
energy use, to year 2000 levels in 2010 ("Phase I") and 1990 levels in
2016 ("Phase II"). Not as restrictive as the U.S. Kyoto target (7
percent below 1990 levels during 2008-2012), but close enough for
government work. Too close, in fact, to be viable in today's political
climate.
To
win new supporters, Sens. McCain and Lieberman have announced they will
introduce an amendment to strike Phase II from the bill. But does
anyone believe for a moment that enacting Phase I would appease rather
than embolden the
More
importantly, any cap on carbon, however modest, would be a
precedent-setting defeat for economic liberty and affordable energy.
The Executive Branch has no authority under current law to regulate CO2
-- the inescapable byproduct of the carbon-based fuels that supply 87
percent of all the energy Americans use. Enacting Phase I would cross a
legal and policy Rubicon, launching an era of energy rationing. There
would no longer exist any difference in kind between
With or without Phase II, McCain's bill would -- like
So
when McCain asks colleagues to support Phase I, he might as well say,
"I just want to put the camel's nose under the tent -- what possible
harm could there be in that?"
Which
raises a more basic question: Why is McCain so blasé about the
potential costs of an open-ended regulatory agenda? The answer is that
McCain believes
Another
study found that the perception that emissions reduction targets such
as those of the Kyoto Protocol are unavoidably costly or unfair is the
result of outdated modeling assessments. In fact, the study
demonstrated how the
The study McCain cites is Cutting Carbon Emissions at a Profit: Opportunities for the U.S.,
published in May 2001 by the International Project for Sustainable
Energy Paths (IPSEP). The IPSEP study, in turn, builds upon Scenarios for a Clean Energy Future
(CEF), a November 2000 analysis prepared by the Interlaboratory Working
Group, a team drawn from the Department of Energy's (DOE's) five
national labs. In all likelihood, few Senators or their staffs have
read CEF, and fewer still have even heard of the IPSEP report. Yet if
McCain's bill has an economic justification, those studies are it.
IPSEP
argues as follows. (1) Implementing the domestic policies detailed in
CEF -- a doubling of public and private funding for energy efficiency
and renewable energy research, development, and demonstration
(RD&D) programs, targeted tax incentives, expansion of efficiency
standards, and the like -- would reduce America's "energy bill" by $60
billion in 2010 and $120 billion in 2020. The concomitant decline in
energy intensity and shift to low- and non-carbon fuels would meet 30
percent of the U.S. Kyoto target in 2010 and half in 2020. (2) Adding a
$65 per ton carbon charge would fully achieve the U.S. Kyoto target in
2010, while a $77 per ton charge would reduce emissions to 20 percent
below 1990 levels in 2020. (3) Capping carbon would raise energy costs
and slow economic growth. However, policymakers could offset any GDP
loss by using the proceeds from carbon taxes or permit sales to cut
taxes on labor and capital. After netting out the positive and negative
impacts, Americans would still reap the "energy bill" savings from the
CEF policies.
Two
problems leap to mind. First, S. 139 omits the only component of
IPSEP's "least-cost strategy" with proven economic value. Tax cuts can
stimulate growth and, in principle, offset GDP losses from carbon
regulation. However, McCain's bill makes no provision for tax cuts.
Instead, following political rather than economic logic, S. 139 would
use the proceeds from carbon permit sales to boost welfare payments
("transition assistance to dislocated workers and communities"), not
GDP. According to IPSEP, cutting taxes on investment would be the most
productive way to "recycle" carbon charges back into the economy.
However, when was the last time McCain's comrade, Sen. Lieberman,
called for tax cuts on dividends, capital gains, or corporate profits?
Second,
McCain and IPSEP ignore opportunity costs. Even if the "least-cost
strategy" worked exactly as advertised, it would not be a free lunch.
Consumers would still lose billions in unrealized GDP growth, because
the economy would be even stronger if Congress just cut taxes on
capital and labor without taxing energy. In addition, the financial,
administrative, and scientific assets dedicated to energy efficiency
and renewable energy programs would compete with RD&D investment in
other high-tech fields. Where is the evidence that, dollar for dollar,
research on, say, wind turbines yields higher economic and
environmental dividends than research on fossil energy exploration and
production technologies?
IPSEP's
"point of departure" is the CEF study by DOE's five labs. IPSEP and
McCain seem completely oblivious to the self-serving nature of that
report. CEF forecasts billions in energy savings if -- but only if --
Congress doubles the labs' RD&D budgets.
Unlike
the DOE labs, the U.S. Energy Information Administration (EIA) has
nothing to gain or lose from adoption or rejection of the CEF policies.
In an October 2001 report [1] requested by Senators Lieberman and Jeffords (I-Vt.), EIA identified several problems in the CEF study.
Hyped RD&D.
"A specific link cannot be established between levels of funding for
research and development and specific improvements in the
characteristics and availability of energy technologies," says EIA.
"Because these funding increases are questionable and the link between
funding and technology development is tenuous, the suggested technology
improvements based on these research and development policies are also
questionable."
EIA
is too kind. CEF's RD&D agenda is mostly old wine in new bottles.
For example, DOE has spent billions over two decades trying to develop
and commercialize non-hydro renewable electric generation. Yet DOE
backing, multi-billion dollar taxpayer and ratepayer subsidies, and
state-level mandates ("portfolio standards") requiring utilities to
deploy such technologies, have not made renewable generation
competitive. Currently, non-hydro renewables contribute less than 3
percent of total
DOE
has not only backed losing horses, it has also failed to invest in
winners. As energy expert Rob Bradley observes: "The fuel of choice for
electricity generation has turned out to be the fuel that the DOE did
not feature in its R&D portfolio -- natural gas." Bradley estimates
that out of $60 billion (in FY96 dollars) expended from FY78 through
FY96, DOE spent only 1 percent ($787 million) on natural gas. [2]
McCain's faith in politically-directed RD&D ignores what MIT's
Thomas Lee, Ben Ball, Jr., and Richard Tabors consider a key "lesson
learned" from previous energy programs: "The experience of the 1970s
and 1980s taught us that if a technology is commercially viable,
then government support is not needed and if a technology is not
commercially viable, no amount of government support will make it so." [3]
Implausible cost and efficiency estimates. CEF
forecasts that, with the right mix of programs, a central air
conditioner with 70 percent greater efficiency than the least efficient
unit would, by 2011, cost no more than the least efficient unit. "It
seems unlikely that either research and development or voluntary
programs could reduce technology costs to that level," comments EIA.
"Other technology assumptions also appear unrealistic -- for example,
the assumption that generating plants using CO2
sequestration technology would achieve the same efficiency as those
that do not." Similarly, EIA finds "extremely unrealistic" CEF's
projection -- "not attributed to any specific policy" -- of a 16
percent per year efficiency increase in natural gas consumption between 2011 and 2020.
Make believe "hurdle" rates.
Consumers and firms do not rush out and buy the latest appliance,
equipment, or vehicle just because the discounted value of future
energy bill savings would exceed the extra cash required to purchase
the most efficient model. Motorists tend to value the utility,
performance, and safety of an automobile more than its fuel economy.
Businesses consider not only whether the returns on an
energy-efficiency investment would exceed the up-front cost, but also
whether other investments would produce higher profits. In markets
where energy costs are expected to decline (the
Consequently,
an energy efficiency investment must have a relatively high rate of
return -- what economists call the "hurdle rate" -- before consumers
and firms will consider it worth the expense. In EIA's analysis, hurdle
rates for the most energy-efficient models can be as high as 83 percent
for electric water heaters, 90 percent for clothes dryers, 125 percent
for room air conditioners, and 391 percent for clothes washers. The CEF
study, by contrast, assumes a 15 percent hurdle rate for all major
appliances. [4]
This assumption, notes EIA, implies that "non-financial factors play no
part" in consumer decisions -- a ludicrous notion. It also means that
consumers are willing to lose money for the sake of energy efficiency,
because "many of these purchases are financed through credit card
accounts with rates above 15 percent."
Low-balled electricity demand.
According to EIA data, electricity consumption for "miscellaneous"
household uses, which include clothes washers, dishwashers, and home
electronics, increased 70 percent from 1990 to 1997. In the CEF
scenarios, electricity demand in this category increases slowly over
the next 20 years. Given the historical growth in miscellaneous uses,
and the fact that some appliances, such as those with heating elements,
cannot incorporate energy efficiency into their design, EIA finds it
"difficult to credit this magnitude of electricity savings from
voluntary programs and State market transformation programs, as stated
in the CEF report." Similarly, EIA finds it "difficult to credit" CEF's
projected energy savings in miscellaneous commercial electricity uses
such as telecommunications equipment, automated teller machines, and
exit signs.
Make believe market failures.
Based on engineering-cost studies, which purport to show handsome
profits from relatively modest efficiency investments, CEF and IPSEP
conclude that market "barriers" and "failures" must be preventing
consumers and firms from seizing so many win-win (good for the economy,
good for the environment) opportunities. EIA rejects that assessment,
noting that "many of the presumed market failures are actually
rational, efficient decisions on the part of consumers given current
technologies, expected prices for energy and other goods and services,
and the value they place on their time to evaluate options."
As
economists Ronald Sutherland and Jerry Taylor point out, when a
homeowner chooses to save his money for junior's college tuition
payment rather than "invest" it in a high efficiency refrigerator, or
declines to install the most efficient air conditioning system because
he plans to sell his house before any net savings would materialize,
that is not a market failure. When markets cater to such revealed
consumer preferences, they are working efficiently. [5]
Studies
like CEF postulate widespread market failure because they confuse
energy efficiency with the efficient use of energy resources. Where
energy is relatively abundant and inexpensive compared to labor and
capital (the long-term
McCain's
bill is a house of cards. Its economic justification is a study (IPSEP)
that proposes tax cuts -- a policy not included in S. 139. That study,
moreover, is built on another (CEF) that exaggerates the prowess of
politically directed RD&D; low-balls advanced technology costs,
consumer hurdle rates, and future energy demand; and proposes to remedy
illusory market failures. Are Senators who may be inclined to support
S. 139 prepared to defend the assumptions, logic, and results of those
studies?
The
Climate Stewardship Act would not be a free lunch, much less the
imagined bonanza of IPSEP's "least-cost strategy," and the economic
damage would grow over time as Phase I evolves into Phases II, III,
etc. But pro-consumer, pro-energy policymakers should take heart. With
a modicum of clarity, discipline, and resolve, they not only can keep
the camel's snout out of the tent, they can also give the beast a
bloody nose.
Marlo Lewis is a senior fellow at the Competitive Enterprise Institute.
NOTES
[1] EIA, Analysis of Strategies for Reducing Multiple Emissions from Electric Power Plants with Advanced Technology Scenarios, October 2001. See especially pp. 14-15, 53-54, 58-59, 85-86
[2] Robert L. Bradley, Jr., Renewable Energy: Not Cheap, Not 'Green,' Cato Policy Analysis, No. 280,
[3] Thomas Lee, Ben Ball, Jr., and Richard Tabors, Energy Aftermath: How We Can Learn From the Blunders of the Past to Create a Hopeful Energy Future (Boston: Harvard Business School Press, 1990), p. 167 (original emphasis).
[4] Interlaboratory Working Group, Scenarios for a Clean Energy Future, November 2000, Appendix A-1.9.